7: Incentives in Natural Law Societies
Summary: Chapter 7 explores the incentives in natural law societies, focusing on environmental, personal, and social responsibility. It contrasts the Pastland society with historical examples from pre-conquest Americas and modern territorial sovereignty societies. The chapter highlights how sharing the bounty of the land creates strong incentives for responsible behavior and community cohesion. It also discusses the limitations of natural law societies, including their lack of incentives for innovation and risk management. The chapter concludes by introducing the concept of a "socratic" society that aims to combine the benefits of natural law societies with incentives for progress.
7: Incentives in Natural Law Societies
Environmental Responsibility Incentives
When we arrived in the ancient past, the land was already healthy. Nature created a balanced ecosystem. If we throw it out of balance, it won’t operate as well as it does now and won’t give us as much wealth as we get now. If we want to keep our incomes high, we will want to make sure that the system remains balanced. We will want to make sure that no harm comes to the land or any part of nature that we depend on.
We would expect these people to have very strong opinions about keeping the land healthy. Any harm to the land could mean a death sentence for them. They will obviously have powerful incentives to make sure that everyone around them is environmentally responsible. If you do something that even has the tiniest potential to harm the land we depend on, you can expect a stern lecture. You will be told that you are harming everyone. (To quote chief Seattle of the Duwamish: ‘Teach your children what we have taught our children that the earth is our mother. Whatever befalls the earth befalls the sons of earth. If men spit upon the ground, they spit upon themselves.’)
A great many different natural law societies existed in the Americas before the conquest. Some had enormous cities, used money for transactions as we do in Pastland, had extensive markets and many goods and services available, just as we have in Pastland. Other groups roamed the land following buffalo or other game, trading meat and livestock products for other goods at pow-wows or other gatherings, and rarely even seeing money. But they all shared a common feature: they all considered nature and the natural world to be unownable and unowned. They all lived on a very bountiful world and shared the bounty.
When Columbus arrived in the Caribbean in October of 1492, very large numbers of people rowed out in canoes to meet him. He had arrived in an area with thousands of islands, each of which produced entirely different things. (Again, for people confused by standard history books that claim that Columbus ‘discovered’ America, it is important to realize that Columbus went to tropical islands in the Caribbean Sea, not to the American continent. Each island has slightly different features and produces different things today; this was also true in 1492.)
Columbus visited many of these islands. He was totally amazed by the incredible health of the land. He had never seen anything like it. Here are his words describing several different islands sequentially:
‘This is a large and level island, with trees extremely flourishing, and streams of water; there is a large lake in the middle of the island, but no mountains: the whole is completely covered with verdure and delightful to behold. The natives are an inoffensive people, and so desirous to possess any thing they saw with us, that they kept swimming off to the ships with whatever they could find, and readily bartered for any article we saw fit to give them in return, even such as broken platters and fragments of glass.
I determined to steer for the largest, which is about five leagues from San Salvador [the name he gave the first island where he landed] the others were some at a greater, and some at a less distance from that island. They are all very level, without mountains, exceedingly fertile and populous’.
Another island:
In the meantime I strayed about among the groves, which present the most enchanting sight ever witnessed, a degree of verdure prevailing like that of May in Andalusia, the trees as different from those of our country as day is from night, and the same may be said of the fruit, the weeds, the stones and everything else.
I assure your Highnesses that these lands are the most fertile, temperate, level and beautiful countries in the world’.
Another island:
This is so beautiful a place, as well as the neighboring regions, that I know not in which course to proceed first; my eyes are never tired with viewing such delightful verdure, and of a species so new and dissimilar to that of our country, and I have no doubt there are trees and herbs here which would be of great value in Spain, as dyeing materials, medicine, spicery, etc., but I am mortified that I have no acquaintance with them. Upon our arrival here we experienced the most sweet and delightful odor from the flowers and trees of the island.
The next island.
The diversity in the appearance of the feathered tribe from those of our country is extremely curious. A thousand different sorts of trees, with their fruit were to be met with, and of a wonderfully delicious odor. It was a great affliction to me to be ignorant of their natures, for I am very certain they are all valuable; specimens of them and of the plants I have preserved.
We will see that some other societies actually have even more powerful incentives to be environmentally responsible than natural law societies. Socratic societies, for example, operate in ways that encourage progress, growth, and mechanization of production with powerful internal reward systems. People will respond to these incentives in ways that cause the land around them to produce more and more with less and less effort and cost. The bounty of the land is the amount left over after subtracting enough to pay the costs. As the total production increases (including production from factories and other facilities on the land) and costs fall, the free cash flow that represents the bounty of the land will increase. The more bounty there is to divide, the more people will get from the land. We will see that healthy land always produces more, at least over the long run, than destroyed land. Socratic societies will have even stronger incentives to be environmentally responsible than natural law societies because people have stronger incentives to care for the land if they get more money from this care than if they get less.
Not all societies that are possible have incentives that encourage environmental responsibility. Some societies have the opposite incentives: they have incentives that encourage irresponsible use of the land. We will look at the flows of value that generate these incentives later in the book, when we look at Territorial sovereignty societies (which have the strongest possible destructive incentives) but, for now, I just want to go over the result.
At the time, hardwood lumber was incredibly valuable in Europe. They weapons factories needed this to make steel. If you want to ‘smelt’ iron, or remove it from rocks, you need to build an extremely hot fire. Wood fires don’t produce enough heat for this, but charcoal made from hardwood does. Europe had been making steel for more than 2,000 years and had basically eliminated all hardwood forests; with no hardwood they couldn’t make steel or more weapons.
Haiti is the native name for the island; in the Tianó language, this word means ‘the mountainous island.’ When the trees were gone, the mountains didn’t have any root systems to hold the soil in place; it began to wash away.
The list of catastrophes is mind-numbing: this week’s devastating earthquake. Four tropical storms or hurricanes that killed about 800 people in 2008. Killer storms in 2005 and 2004. Floods in 2007, 2006, 2003 (twice) and 2002. And that’s just the 21st Century run-down.
This week’s devastating quake comes as Haiti is still trying to recover from 2008, when it was hit four times by tropical storms and hurricanes, said Kathleen Tierney, director of the University of Colorado’s Natural Hazard Center. Every factor that disaster experts look for in terms of vulnerability is the worst it can be for Haiti, said Dennis Mileti, a seismic safety commissioner for the state of California and author of the book Disasters by Design. "It doesn’t get any worse," said Mileti, a retired University of Colorado professor. "I fear this may go down in history as the largest disaster ever, or pretty close to it.".
While nobody knows the death toll in Haiti, a leading senator, Youri Latortue, told The Associated Press that as many as 500,000 could be dead.
We know from history that people who had natural law societies—including the people of the pre-conquest Americas—took truly incredible care of the land around them.
They think that destruction is a part of human nature. If people lived on these lands, in immense numbers for long periods of time, the land would be destroyed. Since the land was not destroyed, they claim that humans could not have actually lived in the Americas, at least not in any numbers or for any length of time.
The book Fact Based History goes over the tools that we use to date artifacts and the evidence we have of a very long period of human habitation in the Americas.
Natural law societies work in ways that provide very real material benefits for people who take care of the land and keep it healthy. The evidence we have tells us that these incentives made a difference.
Personal Responsibility Incentives
Our group in Pastland has a natural law society, at least as long as the moratorium lasts. No one owns the land, so no one owns the wealth it produces. We use part of this wealth to reward/pay people who help bring in the wealth of the land; this leaves the free cash flow, the money value of the bounty of the land.
We have been using part of the free cash that flows from the land to reward people (pay them) for services that benefit everyone. After we pay them, there is still a lot of money left over. We have been dividing this money among our members.
So far, we have been dividing it evenly. I started with this particular distribution of the ‘leftover money’ because it is simple. But we don’t have to divide the leftover money evenly.
We may decide to cut the amounts that go to certain people. Some people may do things that reduce the quality of life for us and some may even do things that cause harm to us. Say that there is a person in our group who picks up things that don’t belong to her and she sees laying around, and then keeps them. We may have people who get into arguments that disturb the peace and quiet, or that stay up late into the night with loud parties that disturb the sleep of those who go to bed early. We can let these people know that we don’t like their behavior in several ways. We may start by simply talking to them and telling them that their behavior bothers us. If this doesn’t work, we may decide to take action by accessing some sort of fine against them for actions that bother us and taking this fine out of their share of the distribution of wealth. We can cut their share of the distribution of wealth from the land, in order to provide incentives for them to consider the feelings of the people around them and act in socially responsible ways.
It is important to realize that this particular option for encouraging social responsibility is not available in all possible societies. Territorial sovereignty societies, for example, consider everything to belong to someone; there are free cash flows, but this money doesn’t flow to the community of humankind and isn’t available for the people to distribute. (In systems where the land is owned, everything the land produces, including its free cash flow, belongs to the owner.) In Territorial sovereignty societies, people who weren’t born rich or don’t have a steady job that can be garnished to get the money don’t really have anything to lose from socially irresponsible behavior. (In some cases, their lives are better if they commit crimes and go to jail, because jail is a better home than they can have any other way. I have known people who have robbed stores and then sat in front of the store waiting for the police, because it is the only way they could get enough to eat.) In natural law societies, there is wealth to divide among the people. People know that if they do things that harm others, the others may vote to reduce their share. In natural law societies, people all have something to lose for acts that harm the people around them.
In our case, most people have two incomes: one comes from the money they earn; the other from their share of the unearned wealth the land produces (its free cash flow). But many people don’t have earned income at all, and many people only get small amounts other than their share of the bounty. These people have very powerful incentives to make sure they don’t cause problems for others and don’t do anything that may even have the appearance of dishonesty.
Personal Responsibility Incentives: Examples
The first day Columbus met the people of the islands of the western hemisphere, Columbus described them this way in his logs:
They are very gentile and without knowledge of what is evil, nor do they murder or steal. Your highness may believe that in all the world there can be no better or gentler people. All the people show the most singular loving behavior and they speak pleasantly. I assure Your Highnesses that I believe than in all the world there is no better people nor better country. They love their neighbors as themselves and they have the sweetest talking the world and are gentle and always laughing.
The most prolific writer of the period, Bartolomé de Las Casas, described them this way:
All the land so far discovered is a beehive of people; it is as though God had crowded into these lands the great majority of mankind. And of all the infinite universe of humanity, these people are the most devoid of wickedness and duplicity. They are by nature the most humble, patient, and peaceable, holding no grudges, free from embroilments, neither excitable nor quarrelsome. These people are the most devoid of rancors, hatreds, or desire for vengeance of any people in the world.
They possess little and have no desire to possess worldly goods. For this reason they are not arrogant, embittered, or greedy. They are very clean in their persons, with alert, intelligent minds. Some of the secular Spaniards who have been here for many years say that the goodness of the Indians is undeniable.
Columbus had an occasion to see how incredibly honest people could be: Columbus had made a friend on the island of Haiti, a man of great respect in the community named ‘Guacanagari.’ Columbus referred to him as ‘the king’ because of the deference that others showed to him. On the 17th of December, Columbus told Guacanagari that in seven days it would be Christmas, the most important holiday for his people. Guacanagari then arranged a feast and celebration in honor of Columbus and his men, to be held as his home on Christmas day. Columbus accepted the invitation and they arranged to meet on Christmas at Guacanagari’s home.
Columbus then went out exploring but was determined to return for the Christmas celebration Guacanagari had arranged.
On December 24, Columbus was on his way from the other side of the island. He had been up for two days straight and was very tired. He had put a sailor on watch and went to bed. The sailor who was in charge was apparently also very tired. He put a cabin boy in charge of the wheel (‘tiller’) and went to bed himself. At midnight, the ship hit a sandbank.
Here is the description of the event from the official logs of the voyage:
December 24, 1492:
Navigating yesterday, with little wind, from Santo Tomas to Punta Santa, and being a league from it, at about eleven o’clock at night the Admiral went down to get some sleep, for he had not had any rest for two days and a night. As it was calm, the sailor who steered the ship thought he would go to sleep, leaving the tiller in charge of a boy. The Admiral had forbidden this throughout the voyage, whether it was blowing or whether it was calm. The boys were never to be entrusted with the helm.
The Admiral had no anxiety respecting sandbanks and rocks, because, when he sent the boats to Guacanagari on Sunday, they had passed to the east of Punta Santa at least three leagues and a half, and the sailors had seen all the coast, and the rocks there arc from Punta Santa, for a distance of three leagues to the E.S.E. They saw the course that should be taken, which had not been the case before, during this voyage.
It pleased our Lord that, at twelve o’clock at night, when the Admiral had retired to rest, and when all had fallen asleep, seeing that it was a dead calm and the sea like glass, the tiller being in the hands of a boy, the current carried the ship on one of the sandbanks.
If it had not been night the bank could have been seen, and the surf on it could be heard for a good league. But the ship ran upon it so gently that it could scarcely be felt. The boy, who felt the helm and heard the rush of the sea, cried out. The Admiral ordered him and others to launch the boat, which was on the poop, and lay out an anchor astern.
The master, with several others, got into the boat, and the Admiral thought that they did so with the object of obeying his orders. But they did so in order to take refuge with the Nina, which was half a league to leeward. The Nina would not allow them to come on board, acting judiciously, and they therefore returned to the ship; but the Nina’s boat arrived first. When the Admiral saw that his own people fled in this way, the water rising and the ship being across the sea, seeing no other course, he ordered the masts to be cut away and the ship to be abandoned.
The master, who was also the owner, of the Admiral’s ship was Juan de la Cosa of Santofia, afterwards well known as a draughtsman and pilot, lightened as much as possible, to see if she would come off. However, as the water continued to rise, nothing more could be done. Her side fell over across the sea, but it was nearly calm. Then the timbers’ opened, and the ship was lost. The Admiral went to the Nina to arrange about the reception of the ship’s crew, and as a light breeze was blowing from the land, and continued during the greater part of the night, while it was unknown how far the bank extended, he hove her to until daylight. He then went back to the ship, inside the reef; first having sent a boat on shore with Diego de Arana of Cordova, Alguazil of the Fleet, and I’edro Gutierrez, Gentleman of the King’s Bedchamber, to inform Guacanagari who had invited the ships to come on the previous Saturday.
His town was about a league and a half (4 miles) from the sandbank.
They reported that he wept when he heard the news, and he sent all his people with large canoes to unload the ship. This was done, and they landed all there was between decks in a very short time. Such was the great promptitude and diligence shown by Guacanagari. He himself, with brothers and relations, were actively assisting as well in the ship as in the care of the property when it was landed, that all might be properly guarded.
Now and then he sent one of his relations weeping to the Admiral, to console him, saying that he must not feel sorrow or annoyance, for he would supply all that was needed. The Admiral assured the Sovereigns that there could not have been such good watch kept in any part of Castille, for that there was not even a needle missing.
He ordered that all the property should be placed by some houses which the king placed at his disposal, until they were emptied, when everything would be stowed and guarded in them. The king and all his people wept. They are a loving people, without covetousness, and fit for anything; and I assure your Highnesses that there is neither better land nor people. They love their neighbors as themselves, and their speech is the sweetest and gentlest in the world, and always with a smile.
‘Your Highnesses should believe that they have very good customs among themselves. The king (Guacanagari) is a man of remarkable presence, and with a certain self contained manner that is a pleasure to see. They have good memories, wish to see everything, and ask the use of what they see’.
Columbus was commanding the Santa Maria, the supply ship for the voyage. The Santa Maria was far larger than the other ships, and laden with many very useful things. Most of these things would have been worth enormous amounts to the natives. When Columbus was trading for these things, the people offered large amounts of gold and skeins of cotton (as valuable as gold at the time to Europeans) for these things.
When they had an easy opportunity to steal them, they declined.
Not so much as a needle was missing.
You and I were born into societies where the great bulk of the people of the world have nothing unless they can get jobs. If they don’t work, they die, regardless of the amount of wealth around them. People in these societies are not rewarded for being personally responsible. In fact, they often must act irresponsibly just to avoid death: if you don’t have a job and have no rich people to give you charity, you must either steal or die. The need to steal is so common that many people don’t even get upset when people steal from them: it is a common part of life and something everyone in business must simply account for: it will happen, and we all know it.
Because theft, deception, and trickery are so common, we all know that we are never really safe in the societies we were born into and which we live in now. People in dire circumstances are behind the shadows of each tree, like ants sweeping the ground for crumbs, waiting to swoop in on any target of opportunity.
This is not the case in all possible societies. Some societies work in ways that generate flows of value that the people as a group may distribute among their members as the group sees fit. Our group in Pastland has $2.4 million left—the free cash flow of the farm—that we can divide any way we want. We want to encourage people to do things that benefit us, so we use part of this money to provide rewards that encourage people to step up and do things that benefit the human race. Some people will find things that we like. If we want to keep having these things, we may give them some of the bounty of the land as a reward, to encourage them to keep doing these things. But we have such enormous amounts of income that, after we pay people who do these things enough to make sure they keep doing them, we have $2 million left. We can divide this money among our people.
If everyone is acting responsibly, it makes sense to divide it evenly. But if some people are acting irresponsible, it wouldn’t make sense to give them an equal share. We may come up with a process of some kind to determine a kind of schedule of offenses. People who violate the rules can be given a hearing and, if the hearing officers conclude that the offense was intentional, they can be fined. This will always reduce the quality of their lives because, as long as the fines are not more than their share of the bounty, they will always be able to afford to pay them. (In Territorial sovereignty societies, most offenders can’t be fined because they have nothing to use to pay the fines. All we can do in this case is put them in jail, which is often a better place to live than they would be living otherwise, so they actually can improve their lives by committing crimes.)
You could say that this system pays everyone to be responsible. In our case, people are paid in money, but all natural law societies have flows of value that must be distributed in some way among the people, so all natural law societies pay or reward for being responsible. If people are rewarded for certain behaviors on a consistent basis, starting at an early age, they become programmed to think about the consequences of their actions. People may see something they want lying around that they know belongs to others. They may have it, but if they realize that they may easily suffer much more than they gain from the object if anyone ever finds out they have it, they will ‘have a feeling’ that it is simply not the right thing to do. Their feelings—actually the ingrained responses of their minds that result from the known relationship between responsible behavior and rewards—will push them to do the responsible thing, whatever they think it is.
Later we will see that we can actually use mathematical analysis to determine the strength of incentives that push toward personal responsibility in different societies. We will see that some societies have very powerful incentives that encourage personal responsibility, some have weaker incentives, some have none at all, and some even have incentives that discourage personal responsibility. We will see that natural law societies have very strong incentives that encourage personal responsibility, but they aren’t the strongest possible. (Socratic societies, discussed later in the book, have much stronger incentives pushing toward social responsibility, because of rapid increases that drive up the bounty of the world; if the world is more bountiful, there is more to divide and people have more to gain from personal responsibility.) But, although it is possible to have ‘personal responsibility incentives’ that are stronger than those in natural law societies, natural law societies have extremely strong incentives to come to understand the rules and act properly. We can see from the historical records that these incentives really did exist in these societies when they dominated the western half of the world.
Columbus was amazed at the honesty of the people in the new world, as the excerpts from his logs presented above show. Others expressed the same amazement:
The official historian of the Spanish Crown during the time that Columbus was alive was a Dutchman named ‘Peter Myrtar.’ Myrtar was very impressed by the honesty of the people of the lands he studied. He studied the people and came to the conclusion that there is something about the idea of sharing the land and the things the land produced that led to this behavior. Here are some quotes from his official report on the people of the new world, called ‘Orbo Novo’ (The New World):
It is proven that amongst them the land belongs to everybody, just as does the sun or the water. They know no difference between meum and tuum, that source of all evils. It requires so little to satisfy them, that in that vast region there is always more land to cultivate than is needed. It is indeed a golden age, neither ditches, nor hedges, nor walls to enclose their domains; they live in gardens open to all, without laws and without judges; their conduct is naturally equitable, and whoever injures his neighbor is considered a criminal and an outlaw.
He goes on:
They know neither weights nor measures, nor that source of all misfortunes, money; living in a golden age, without laws, without lying judges, without books, satisfied with their life, and in no wise solicitous for the future.
Bartolomé de Las Casas was the most prolific writer of the time. Here he describes these same people:
Of all the infinite universe of humanity, these people most devoid of wickedness and duplicity; they are by nature the most humble, patient, and peaceable, holding no grudges, free from embroilments, neither excitable nor quarrelsome. These people are the most devoid of rancors, hatreds, or desire for vengeance of any people in the world.
What about these same lands now?
You can find many descriptions of the changes that occurred in the first few years after the arrival of the Europeans in the book Fact Based History. They show that the Europeans made a dedicated effort to wipe out the old social order and replace it with a new one on the European model. They succeeded. The payments that went to responsible people are no longer being made; they haven’t been made for centuries. The Europeans needed lumber very badly to make charcoal for steel. Haiti, the first island they settled, was densely forested and the Europeans clear cut it. The Europeans took the gold and other metals and then abandoned the useless hulk that remained. The Europeans decimated the native population, generally by enslaving them and working them to death. By 1540 there weren’t enough natives left to fill the Christian need for slaves, so the Europeans began bringing in both white slaves (purchased from European prisons) and black slaves (captured and enslaved from Africa) to finish raping the lands. Once the land had been denuded of anything valuable, the slave masters basically abandoned it. They left the descendents of the white and black slaves they had imported; these people interbred with the native people that remained to create the racial mixture we see on the island of Haiti today. (DNA studies show that a large percentage of the people of Haiti have ancestors of all three races.)
These people did not have anything to work with: the ecosystem that had supported the natives, and that early European arrivals had marveled at, no longer existed: all resources valuable to the outside world were gone.
The former masters who abandoned this island did leave these people with something however: they left them with an administrative system based on the principles of sovereignty, as accepted in Europe. These people had an entirely different foundation to build on than the people who lived before them.
How did things turn out? You can get some idea from the next quote. This quote is from the United States government’s travel advisory website, for the exact same island described in the above passages, the one with no ‘murder or theft’ (according to Columbus) where ‘their conduct is naturally equitable, and whoever injures his neighbor is considered a criminal and an outlaw’ according to Myrtar, where ‘these people most devoid of wickedness and duplicity of all the infinite universe of humanity’ reside.
Reconsider travel to Haiti due to crime and civil unrest. Violent crime, such as armed robbery, is common. Protests, tire burning, and road blockages are frequent and often spontaneous. Local police may lack the resources to respond effectively to serious criminal incidents, and emergency response, including ambulance service, is limited or non-existent.
Travelers are sometimes targeted, followed, and violently attacked and robbed shortly after leaving the Port-au-Prince international airport. The U.S. Embassy requires its personnel to use official transportation to and from the airport, and it takes steps to detect surveillance and deter criminal attacks during these transports.
The U.S. government has limited ability to provide emergency services to U.S. citizens in some areas of Haiti. The Embassy discourages its personnel from walking in most neighborhoods. The Embassy prohibits its personnel from:
Visiting establishments after dark without secure, on-site parking.
Using any kind of public transportation or taxis.
Visiting banks and using ATMs.
Driving outside of Port-au-Prince at night.
Traveling anywhere between 1:00 a.m. and 5:00 a.m..
Visiting certain parts of the city at any time without prior approval and special security measures in place.
If you decide to travel to Haiti:
Avoid demonstrations.
Arrange airport transfers and hotels in advance, or have your host meet you upon arrival.
Be careful about providing your destination address in Haiti. Do not provide personal information to unauthorized individuals located in the immigration, customs, or other areas inside or near any airports in Haiti.
As you leave the airport, make sure you are not being followed. If you notice you are being followed, drive to the nearest police station immediately.
Do not physically resist any robbery attempt.
Social Responsibility Incentives
What is the most irresponsible thing someone could do in a social situation?
How about this: the person could organize a gang to use murder and terror to either drive off or kill all people who are not in her gang. Then she could claim that the part of the world she and her gang live on belongs to the gang and she will kill any who try to cross the borders into her territory. This is the kind of system that territorial apes like gorillas and chimps had. It is the kind of system territorial dogs like wolves and hyenas have. It is also the kind of system humans have today. The territories controlled by gangs are the things we call ‘countries.’
You and I were raised in a crazy world. The schools in our world today teach children that their highest allegiance is not to their race, not to their culture, not to nature, not to the world around them, but to their country. They are taught that the greatest heroes in history where the ones who organized the mass murder events called ‘wars’ that led to their country existing and then fought off any who even considered trying to benefit from anything inside the borders of the countries. Children are raised to believe it is not just acceptable, but admirable to be willing to kill others and inflict terror on any who threaten the interests of their country. In many areas, the mass murder is required: the system classifies any who refuse to become part of the killing machines as criminals.
Our group in Pastland has passed a moratorium. For the time this moratorium is in effect, we will not allow any person or group to form into a gang to take control of any territory. Natural law societies that existed in the past rest on the same basic principle. The primary law of this society—we may call it a ‘prime directive’ if we want to use Star Trek terminology—is that no one may organize to use violence to create a country. We have only one offense that is so serious that we will not allow any who commit it to remain among us: you may not organize for violence to force others to accept a country. Anyone who commits this offense will be evicted from orderly society and sent to live in the wild. Since individuals sent to live in the wild will almost certainly not be able to survive, this is effectively a death sentence.
Pep who might consider organizing for mass murder or terror against others will realize that they can’t possibly gain from this. Either they will be caught early and suffer the consequences of having violated primary laws or, if they can organize a gang and start murdering, they will be wiped out by the great majority, that will do everything it can to prevent the success of this takeover.
We may understand how hard it would be to break away from a community like this and form a country if we consider that the societies in the Americas existed for at least 10,000 years without anyone successfully creating a country. Almost certainly, people tried to do so. People are self-interested. This is true in any society. Self-interested people want more for themselves. Any distribution of wealth that favors any individual or small group will effectively grant ownership rights for that individual or small group. This violates our prime directive. It is the one activity we can’t allow.
Of course, over the course of 10,000 years, a lot of people would try to find some tricky way to make the others accept that they had special rights to the land. People trying to get more for themselves can be very clever. But the fact that this didn’t happen over the course of 10,000 years tells us how hard it is to do it. How are you going to react if someone tries to trick you into accepting she has special rights to a part of the world in Pastland? Even if she can convince you of this, she won’t be able to get these rights unless she can trick the majority of the people. If this were easy to do, surely someone would have been able to do it in the enormous period of time that people lived in the Americas.
The book Fact Based History deals with this issue from a wider perspective. Forensic evidence tells us that humans have been on Afro-Eurasia for 350,000 years. Countries leave very clear artifacts. We know when these institutions first came to exist because, as soon as countries appeared, the special artifacts that are associated with countries appeared. We can’t find any of these artifacts going back more than 6,000 years. This tells us that humans existed on the Afro-Eurasian landmass for at least 344,000 years before the first group was able to form the first successful country. (We will see, when we look at Territorial sovereignty societies, that once one successful country exists, the country-based system spreads very rapidly and conquers additional land.) This means that, for more than 98% of the time humans lived on the Afro-Eurasian landmass, the people there were able to successfully resist all attempts to create countries.
As we will see shortly, the ideas of sovereignty and countries can spread extremely quickly once they take hold. But the point here is that there will be almost universal resistance to the very ideas that the societies we have now encourage and foster. The idea of fighting, killing, and committing terror to force the majority of the people of the world to accept special rights for the minority would be seen as the most wrong of all possible wrongs. Nothing could inspire more guilt in the heart of someone raised in a natural law society than the idea of doing the things that are fostered and encouraged in Territorial sovereignty societies. Nothing would be more likely to lead to action by the authorities and condemnation by all of the people than advocating murder and terror to gain special rights for minorities at the expense of the majority. (No country in the world includes a majority of the people of the world; this means that all activities that are designed to advance the interests of countries are designed specifically to benefit minorities at the expense of the majority.)
General Incentives Of Natural Law Societies
Natural law societies naturally foster three very important kinds of incentives:
1. Incentives to do things
that keep the land healthy and environmental clean.
2. Incentives to be personally
responsible and honest.
3. Incentives to be responsible
socially (essentially, to not organize for murder and terror).
We may label these as ‘desirable incentives.’
Natural law societies also produce what we may call 'undesirable incentives.’
They reward activities that harm society or, to put this another way, they discourage people from doing things that need to be done to make society function smoothly and productively. Some of the incentives of natural law societies expose the people in these societies to incredible risks, for example, by making it effectively impossible to manage risk. As a result, many groups of people with natural law societies are totally wiped out by events that would not have had any significant impact on them if they had been able to manage risk.
Other incentives if natural law societies actively discourage some of the most desirable behaviors of humankind. Humans are smart. We are inventive. We are creative. We have a sort of internal desire to try to make life better for ourselves and the other people around us. We want to find ways to do things better than people have done them before. We want to find ways to manage risk and prevent harm for the people around us. Unfortunately, natural law societies work in ways that essentially punish people who try to make the world better.
The general idea here is much easier to see with examples and we will look at many, many examples later in the book. If you must pay more in costs than you get in benefits to do things that bring benefits to the human race, you personally suffer for making them. Any society that works in ways that makes the costs of these behaviors higher than the benefits punishes behaviors that benefit the human race, something that makes life worse for us all. When we look at many societies and compare them, we will see that natural law societies impose the greatest possible punishments on behaviors that benefit society.
Some societies work in ways that encourage beneficial behaviors. In societies built on the idea of personal ownership of rights, including TS societies, people can buy and own rights to part of the streams of benefits that improvements can bring. (People who find ways to make life better for people can patent their idea, for example and, for a time, make great profits doing these things. Their improvement will benefit the human race forever. The people who made the improvement get rich for the rest of their lives. Although this often seems unfair (because of the enormous wealth these people get for a tiny amount of effort), the real beneficiary is the human race. Our existence is better forever.
The book Possible Societies examines the ways different types of societies work in various ways. It shows that societies can work in ways that reward destructive behaviors. Such societies have ‘destructive incentives.’ Societies can also work in ways that reward beneficial behaviors. Such societies have ‘constructive incentives.’ Natural law societies have no real destructive incentives, but they don’t have any constructive incentives either. Because constructive behaviors are essential for survival of the human race, natural law societies can’t work over the long term to meet the needs of the human race. (That should be clear by the end of this chapter.)
Our group in Pastland has unintentionally formed a natural law society. We are not going to keep it. To see why, we need to look at the downside. We need to look at the reason this society won’t work for us. The next chapter goes over what we may call the ‘undesirable incentives’ of natural law societies, or, to put this another way, it goes over the desirable incentives that could exist in society, which did exist in the TS societies we had before we went back in time, and which we could bring to our society in Pastland if we want to do this, without having to get rid of the desirable incentives.
This is possible
because the desirable and undesirable incentives come from entirely different
flows of value. We have incentives that
foster and encourage environmental responsibility (a harmonious relationship
with the environmental), personal responsibility (a lack of crime), and social
responsibility (a lack of divisiveness that would otherwise make organized
conflict possible) because we share the bounty of the world. In all societies where people share the
bounty, they have incentives to make the land as bountiful as possible and to
maintain good relationships with the community as a whole (because the
community decides how the bounty is shared and will likely exclude people who
do things that harm them.)
The beneficial incentives come
from a flow of value that I will call 'marginal production.' In economics, the term ‘marginal production’
refers to increases in production above the current level. (The bounty only comes from basic production, which means the
production that already takes place.
This is true under the definition of ‘free cash flow’ which this book
uses to refer to the bounty. The free
cash flow only refers to the cash that already flows from the property when the
current manager/owner became involved.
Any increase in the cash flow is not ‘free,’ it is earned. I think you will find it easier to
understand this with examples and a great many examples follow.)
If two incentive streams
result from two different flows of value, it is possible to adjust them
separately and independently. In other
words, you can keep the desirable incentives by keeping the flow of value that
creates them. (As long as the people of
the world share the bounty of the world, the desirable incentives will remain
in place.) At the same time, you can
get rid of the undesirable incentives of natural law societies by making
changes that take the flows of value that create them away from the human race.
(In other words, make it possible for private individuals to buy and own
the rights to marginal production.)
This is the basic idea behind the socratic. It is designed to bring the interests of individuals into alignment with the interest of the human race by creating a system where the basic productivity of the world (its bounty, essentially) goes to the human race and the marginal productivity is under private control (people can make money if they improve the world).
Chapter 7: SEO Snippet: Natural law societies foster environmental and social responsibility through shared bounty, but lack incentives for innovation. Socratic societies aim to balance both.
Keywords: Natural law societies, Environmental responsibility, Social incentives, Land bounty sharing, Socratic society model